Felix Stalder, PhD Student,
Faculty of Information Studies, University of Toronto
felix@openflows.org

for Derrick DeKerckhove, McLuhan Program in Culture and Technoloy

Media, Mind, Society, 1996

January 1997


    Note: This text has exploratory character. Non-commercial use is encouraged. Commercial use only with my written consent. I appreciate feedback. F.S.

    Last update: May, 1997

    Table of Contents


    1. Introduction

    2. The financial markets, a sketch
    2.1. The origins
    2.2. Some basic figures

    3. Elements of the markets
    3.1. Derivatives
    3.2. Forecasting approaches
    3.3. The clearinghouse

    4. The nature of networks
    4.1. Networks as environment
    4.2. Face value and cooperation
    4.3. Convergence
    4.4. The paradox of control

    5. Outlook: development without control?

    6. Bibliography


    "The two great inventions of the human mind are writing and money-the common language of intelligence and the common language of self-interest."
    Mirabeau (quoted in Innis, 1951, p.8)


    1. Introduction

    Karl Marx wrote in Grundrisse, Foundations of a Critique of Political Economy (1857): "Money as medium of circulation becomes coin, mere vanishing moment, mere symbol of value it exchanges. ... As the most superficial (in the sense of driven out onto the surface) and the most abstract form of the entire production process [money circulation] is in itself quite without content." (quoted in: Spivak, 1987, p.32) In this sense, money circulation1 is a 'pure medium', much as light was a pure medium in the eyes of Marshall McLuhan, a medium without content.

    The underlying thesis of this short paper is that financial networks offer a uniquely transparent view on the dynamics of networks in their pure form. The nature of networks itself becomes visible in the workings of the financial markets.

    The financial markets are, unlike any other aspect of today's economy or culture, completely embedded in computer networks, many of its instruments are unthinkable in any other media environment. Their phenomenal growth over the last two decades is a direct result of the power created by the linking of high-end computational hard- and software with nearly unlimited, or at least abundant, telecommunicational bandwidth2.

    The long-term perspective of my interest is to describe the structure and nature of computer-based communication networks to determine their impact on society and culture. The area of electronic money can serve as an empirical testing ground to discern patterns that will be more difficult so see in other areas where they are likely to be 'distorted' as they form combinations with patterns of other environments, their different natures and modes of structuring.

    Evidently, this paper is only a first step into that direction and it's goal is mainly to test a number of speculations and to present preliminary results.

    The first section will sketch the origins and the present state of the financial markets3, the second section will describe some of its mechanisms and the tools employed and the final section will interpret the findings in the light of their 'networkness', it will try to abstract from the empirical evidence, an analysis of the inherent culture4 of networks.5

    2. The financial markets, a sketch


    2.1. The origins

    In the 19th century the nation-states began to (re)form around national economies under the influence of liberal and later conservative economic theorists the introduction of the gold standard marked an important shift of power from the ruling aristocracy to the market and the merchants. Until then, a method of balancing the budget popular among rulers was to change the gold to metal ratio in the coins, in other words, to start inflation. This habit complicated the money exchange and international trade enormously. Inspired by ideas of the political economist David Ricardo (1772-1823) the gold standard6 was created in England in the first half of the 19th century. By 1880 all major countries had adopted this standard (Eichengreen, 1985). The gold standard remained valid until W.W.I and was reintroduced 1944 in the Bretton Woods agreements regulating the post-war international economy (Millan, 1995, p.43, Eichengreen 1996). Ironically, the end of the gold standard, 1971, marked again a shift of power from the political ruler, this time the nation-state, to the markets and the merchants.

    Several independent developments increased the power of the markets culminating in end of the gold standard, trends most visible in the emergence of the Eurodollar7.

    • After the W.W.II Russia and other 'Iron Curtain' countries held US $ but couldn't invest those in the United States because they feared the possible seizure for political reasons. But since the US $ were for the Soviet government without value inside the USSR itself, they had to be brought into the western economy. This was done through a Soviet owned bank in France, the 'Banque Commercial du l'Europe du Nord'. The bank lent the dollars to others non-US banks in Europe and created the first market for money outside the control of the issuing government. It bears some irony that the communist regimes were amongst the originators of a development that would eventually lead to a truly global capitalism.

    • After W.W.II an increasing amount of US $ left the United States. The Marshall Plan, for example, poured enormous sums into Europe and not all of it was used to buy US goods, some of it stayed in the allied countries.

    • In the 1950s large enterprises began to expand into foreign countries. This trade and manufacturing driven development was backed by an increasingly multinational banking infrastructure. In 1960 only 8 US banks had foreign branches, 1978 more than 100 US banks had 761 foreign branches. (Hamelink, 1984 p. 61) The international trade was mainly done in US $ and more US $ flowed in foreign countries.

    • The infrastructure that enabled international money transfer was used to circumvent American restrictions. The US government, under the impact of the 1929 Crash and the Great Depression that followed, had defined a ceiling for interest rates, the so-called 'Regulation Q'. No such limit existed in Europe and when the rates began to rise there over the US limit, money was transferred to Europe to seek a higher yield. (Valdez, 1993, p.112)

    • Since the 1950s the expansion of the telecommunication infrastructure around the globe increased the possibilities and decreased the prices of transnational real time communication. The transatlantic cable that was laid for telephone voice transmission in 1956 could carry 36 very expensive conversations at one time. In 1976 the sixth cable was laid, it could carry 4,000 conversations at one time, 1988 the first fiber-optic cable was laid, it could carry 40,000 conversations at once (Wriston, 1992, pp. 42-44).

    During this time of rapid transnational expansion, the ratio of money to gold remained relatively stable at ten to one (Hammond, 1996, p.148). However, in the 1960s the system of fixed currency exchange started to become too inflexible to represent an increasingly dynamic international economy. The political problems, such as the crisis of France (May 68), played a certain role in accelerating the destabilization of the international financial system as it had existed since W.W.II (Millan 1995, pp.65-94, Eichengreen, 1996). In 1971 when the system broke down and erstwhile president Richard Nixon abolished the gold standard, the 'Eurodollars' became the seeds of new electronic money and the global financial markets (Kurtzman, 1993, p.85).

    2.2. Some basic figures


    The preconditions for the global capital markets were not created in any planed way, they evolved in the crossing of several independent trends. They did not emerge by themselves or unintended, nor are they developing without major, very intended and targeted investment. Underlying and forming these markets is a very extensive infrastructure that requires increasingly heavier investment to be kept up-to-date. The 10 largest US investment banks, for example, spent in 1980 2 billion and 1995 17 billion on new technologies (Lowell; Farrell, 1996 p.41). This equals roughly the research investment of the US pharmaceutical industry (Kurtzman, 1993, p.26). Over the same period the number of people working in these institutions rose from 17,000 to 41,000. The total number of people working in the global financial markets is estimated to be 500,0008 (Lowell; Farrell 1996 pp.52-53). The financial markets consist world wide of some 6,400 institutions that are directly involved in the process of dealing9.

    While those investments represent more the intra-company infrastructure that is required to successfully participate in these markets, the markets themselves, or at least an important part of them, take place in the semi-public10 arena of the closed private information networks, such as the financial networks of Reuters. Reuters, which started in 1850 with a pigeon carrier to send stock exchange data from Brussels to Aachen in order to bridge the gap between the Belgian and the German telegraph lines (Read, 1992), is today's leading provider of news to the financial markets, a service that is delivered over a proprietary network. It brings news and prices directly to customer screens, providing datafeeds to financial markets, and the software tools to analyze the data. This data covers currencies, stocks, bonds, futures, options and other instruments. Its main customers are the world's leading financial institutions, traders, brokers, dealers, analysts, investors and corporate treasurers. Even though the there are several competitors in these markets, Reuters regards itself as "a market leader in most of these sectors." (From the Reuters webpage)

    However, Reuters does not only provide the news for the market, Reuters is also the environment of the markets themselves. It provides the tools for dealers to contact counterparts through a Reuters communications network in order to do the actual tradings. Through proprietary instruments, such as Dealing 2000-211, Reuters enables traders to deal from their keyboards in such markets as foreign exchange, futures, options, and securities. Foreign exchange dealers can either converse with chosen trading partners or use an automated matching system.

    The underlying size and potential of these communicational services are well kept company secrets. If the revenue is any indicator of the company's activities then the financial services are about 10 times bigger than the traditional news agency, which only yields less than 10% of the company's revenues, but still is the largest of its kind worldwide. (Read, 1992, The Annual Report 1993, p. 25)

    The effective size of the financial markets is difficult to determine, since the sources are often not comparable. However, a few key figures may serve as an indicator of the enormous amounts of money that circulates in these markets. The foreign exchange market, virtually unexisting in the early 70s, was the first sector of the financial market to globalize and still is in many aspects the only real global market12. In the mid 70s their daily turnover rate was $15 billion, since then it has expanded to $60 billion/day in 1980, to $300billion/day in 1986, and to (more than) $1 trillion/day in 1995. Only about 1.5-3% of that sum is connected to the world trade, the movement of physical commodities from one currency system into another and the world trade is no triviality (Sassen, 1996, p.40). The rest is purely the virtual movement of money, done by banks and foreign currency speculators, without any direct relation to physical goods13.

    Virtual, however, does not mean without real gains. For most of the banks this from of trading has developed into one of the most profitable areas of business. Citibank, one of the leading banks worldwide, made in the early1990s an average of $500 million/year profit in the foreign currency exchange market. The US comptroller of currency calculates that foreign currency exchange dealing accounts for half of the profits made by the big commercial banks during that period (Valdez, 1993, p.126).

    An other figures estimates that at the same time the overall daily exchange within the world's financial center, NYC, was about $ 1.9 trillion/day. Within 3 days this equals the total output of American companies and it's work force of one year (Kurtzmann, 1993 p.17).

    Ray Hammond, in his 1996 book Digital Economy, presents an even more impressive figure estimating that 90% of the world's wealth is transmitted from account to account over the closed financial networks (Hammond, 1996, p.154).

    Such comparisons are somewhat problematic because it is dubious whether these figures are really comparable in any meaningful way. The quality of the values that circulate around the globe is fundamentally different from that stored in physical goods, such as real estate or machinery. Money within the networks represents a informational flow and as such it is dependent on the qualities of flows, which are determined by factors as speed and the number of participants. In contrast, the values stored in physical goods represent possession, and as such they are subject to completely other dynamics, dependent on scarcity and physical location.

    In spite of conceptual ambiguities, the capital markets represent today one of the most important power centres in the developing global culture. They emerged into this role trough innovation in previously unexisting territory, the electronic networks. The rationale of seeking these possibilities has always been exclusively to search for a higher yield, capitalizing on and accelerating long range social and economic trends. The markets and their instruments developed outside any direct governmental control, driven by profit seeking, and enabled by technology.

    The following section takes a short look at three elements of the capital markets, as they developed in the last few years. The first is a financial instrument, derivatives, the second are models for forecasting and the third is a controlling institution, the clearinghouse.

    3. Elements of the markets


    3.1. Derivatives


    Derivatives is a general term for a number of different financial products, such as futures, options and swaps. What they have in common is that they are "bilateral contracts that are used for the exchange of the risks and returns of holdings assets. They are called derivatives because the value of a derivative contract varies with the fluctuations in the value of the underlying asset. That is, the value of the contract is 'derived' from the value of the underlying asset." (Lowell, Farrell, 1996 p.41)

    To simplify matters, I will use the example of options to sketch the basic features of derivatives in general.

    An option conveys a right, but not the obligation to buy (or sell) stock, bond or any other financial instrument at a specific time for a specific price. This right can be traded. It is separate from but related to the price of the underlying product. An option is an instrument to speculate on the future movement of the markets. If a dealer expects the market to rise, he or she can pay the holder of an asset for the right to buy it within or after a period, usually 1-12 month, for a fixed price. If the market rises over the prearranged price then the dealer exercises the option and buys the underlying asset, only to sell it immediately to the higher market price. The profit arises from the difference between the actual market price and the prearranged price in the option. If the market moves in the other direction, then the dealer does not have to exercise the option, it simply expires and the dealer looses what he or she paid for the option.

    Options an be understood as a second, and if they are traded as a third, fourth or fifth layer of abstraction in order to gain control over more assets than otherwise possible. Instead of buying the 'real' asset for 100% of its actual price, an option can be bought for, let's say, 5% granting the right to buy the asset in the future. If the price of the asset rises then the option is exercised if not, the option expires. With this mechanism very small movements of the underlying asset can have very significant impacts.

    Evidently, there is no sure gain in speculation. If the price of the underlying asset moves downwards, let's say 1%, then the speculator looses 100% because it would make no sense to exercises the option and buy the underlying asset at a price higher than it would be currently available on the market14.

    The powerful element of derivatives is not only that they allow speculation on relative small market movements but also that they are indefinitely expandable and that they allow to tie together originally unrelated things. Really complex derivatives may give, to quote Kevin Kelly, "the option of buying milk at a certain price in New Zealand while simultaneously selling oil in Taiwan. Third- and fourth-order derivatives -- those betting on an option based on a bet that hinges on another gamble -- increase the complexity and incomprehensibility of these financial instruments" (Kelly, 1994b).

    As an effect, the markets that were previously unrelated become more and more integrated (Millan, 1994, p.xiii) and the number of factors to be taken into account rises exponentially. In such an environment, where many factors influence the movements and tiny movements can be translated into massive consequences forecasting becomes more important, more rewarding, and, more complex. Traditional models have lost their usefulness for predicting the movement of prices in such an environment and alternative models are being developed to monitor the new territories.

    3.2. Forecasting approaches


    Two principally different forecasting approaches exist in the financial markets: fundamental analysis and technical analysis. Fundamental analysis is a technique of modeling the market based on the movement of fundamental economic variables. Its underlying concept is that the financial markets represent directly in a linear and deterministic way the traditional economy. The financial markets are, according to this model, the dependent variable while the 'real' economy is the independent one. In terms of communication theory: the real economy is the input and the financial markets are the out put. In short, this approach is rooted in the classical Newtonian logic that every effect (the financial market) has an independent cause (the physical economy).

    In contrast, technical analysis tries to recognize the patterns within the movements of prices in the financial markets. As a method it started in the 1950s when the first scientists and researchers claimed to predict the markets more efficiently by looking at the past behaviour of the segment in question than by analyzing the fundamental variables. To do so they began to draw huge charts, hence their name "Chartists", to make patterns visible to the naked eye and use this insight as the basis of forecasting (Mills, 1992).

    Predicting the future especially in the financial markets is somewhat paradoxical, because it contradicts one of the corner-stones of the neo-liberal economic theory, "the efficient market hypothesis" (Mills, 1992). An efficient, open market is believed to incorporate all knowledge immediately leading to randomness in the movement of the prices. The unpredictability is the result of independent participants who try to use information before others can use it . This constant feedback of information to the markets guarantees the efficiency that everyone has the same information. Predictability, as it turns out, is the sign of an inefficient market itself.

    How deeply the nature of the markets changed since they have become network-based is reflected in the landslide in popularity between the two forecasting models. Since the late 70s or early 80s the number of practitioners of fundamental analysis in the financial markets has fallen sharply and the number of technical analysts risen considerably (Metha, 1995 p.184). A new environment needs new conceptual models.

    The old model of fundamental analysis came to its limits on several levels:

    • The increasing inability to define and comprehend what the fundamental variables are.
    • The rapid flow of information and its significant influence on the market movement.
    • The need to be able of react in this fast paced environment.
    • Increased short term volatility and the new opportunities arising from that.
    • Rapid development of computer technology to address multi-dimensional problems (Metha, 1995, pp.187-188).

    The current models for the markets move away from the analysis of the interconnection between the markets and the underlying economy. The more the markets are seen as interconnected the more the impact of 'distortions' - the self produced side-effects - are taken into focus. New models take into account that the independent variables can no longer be defined15, and also that the systems as such becomes increasingly non-linear. This results for the following reasons:

    • The increasing coupling of different microstructures of connected but independent markets by instruments such as derivatives multiplies not only the variables but also, exponentially, the number of their interconnections.
    • Market psychology becomes more important as the speed of the transactions increases and leads to nonlinear feedback mechanisms in price movements: If a price gets too high and starts to sink, then it usually sinks under the price that would be appropriate. This is due to fact that the markets tends to overreact on bad and underreact on good news.
    • 'Market imperfections' such as transaction cost and regulations influence the behaviour. To minimize these costs transactions tend to cluster. (Apostolos-Paul, 1995, pp.ix-x)

    Today, it is the prevailing wisdom of financial economist, that the price fluctuations not due to external influences [news] are dominated by noise and they can be modeled by stochastic processes. The models for such an environment are based on completely or partially deterministic but nonlinear dynamics.

    Such models are rooted in artificial intelligence and especially in neural networks as self-learning systems. In the financial world, the interest in 'intelligence' is very prosaic. What makes it worth the heavy investment is the promise that artificial intelligence can make statistical inferences without any a priori assumptions about the data and that 'intelligent' systems are therefore capable of detecting dependencies despite complex, nonlinear behaviour.

    These systems try to make use of what chaos theory calls the two kinds of complexity: inherent and apparent complexity. Inherent complexity is the 'true' complexity of chaotic systems. It leads to final unpredictability. The other kind of complexity is the compliment of chaos. Apparent complexity only looks like chaos, but with the right mathematical concepts, the veil of obscurity can be lifted and an exploitable order appears. These two forms of complexity make chaotic systems unpredictable in the long run, but in the short term there are patterns leading to predictable behaviour. "The key question to ask in beating the stock market is, what patterns should you pay attention to? Which ones disguise order? Learning to recognize order, not causes, is the key." (Kelly, 1994b)

    The rise of the pattern-oriented models represents a paradigm shift in the cognition of observable activities. This shift is directly related to the nature of the environment and the new paradigms of interconnected networks. The models applied are principally different from the ones that build on classical Newtonian logic. They assume no relationship between the financial markets and the underlying economy. This does not imply that there is non, but for the successful player this long-term relationship is simply not relevant, his cycles move at a completely different speed. In the currency markets fortunes are made within minutes, hours or days and not within months or years.

    Instead of analyzing the vertical relationship between underlying cause and its derived effect, the alternative models focus on how effects reproduce themselves horizontally and what this reveals about their inherent dynamics. The model is built on the assumption it is the effect that moves the effect in a constant feedback loop instead of a linear cause-effect relation. The search for pattern replaces the search for reasons.

    The patterns in complex systems, however, are tricky. They are, at best, only reliable for very short moments, in the terms of the economic theory, these are the market inefficiencies. The small pockets of predictability. However, they help to navigate in an volatile, fast-paced environment. Considering the huge amounts of money involved, even a small reliability can be worth a lot. Random guessing has a chance to make the right choice of 50% since there are only to possibilities, buy or sell. If a complex system can augment these chances by 10-20 percentage points then this system could yield a fortune, much higher than the average return in the financial markets.

    Huge amounts of money slosh in virtually unpredictable patterns through the global communication system. To keep that flow uninterrupted at such a high speed, technical connectivity and sophisticated analytical methods are needed but also a structural context that assures a certain, and in the case of the financial markets, absolute reliability.

    In the physical world this context of reliability is built either through direct knowledge of the other, through the presentation of trustworthy additional information such as passport or credit card or by researching otherwise available data about the person, such as credit history, criminal records, work reports etc.

    The first method is obviously not applicable in a global economy. But also the other methods have common weaknesses:
    They are slow, and
    They rely on a trusted third party, such as the nation-state as the legitimate issuer of the passport.

    To guarantee the necessary reliability in the network environment without any slow-down of the flow of information the financial markets established several institutions, one of them is the clearinghouse.

    3.3. The clearinghouse


    The first clearinghouse was founded by the Chicago Board of Trade in 187416. It was originally set up to facilitate the settlements of expiring contracts but soon assumed a wider role. By acting as a seller to all buyers and as a buyer to all sellers, it became the guarantor of ultimate fulfillment of the contract. Thus contracts could be exchanged impersonally between numerous parties on both sides without each having to worry about the others ability or willingness to actually carry out their obligations (Houthakker, 1996, p.233). Its function is to guarantee the execution of outstanding futures and other contracts. A clearinghouse can be understood as an outsourced and institutionalized trust to cope with an anonymous and chaotic environment.

    A clearinghouse is a legally independent entity but it is usually connected with an exchange facility. It works upon two premises:

    • 1. It requires the deposit, the margin, from its members, a limited number of very substantial firms. This deposit can be used if the clearinghouse has to actually fulfill its guarantee and pay if one side of a deal defaults.
    • 2. The liability of the clearinghouse is, practically, infinite. Members of the clearinghouse can be called on for additional funds in emergencies. Theoretically, the clearinghouse can draw back upon the entire funds of its members to fulfill its guarantees. But, embedded in a very complex legal systems of securing, this has never happened in the US and is virtually impossible (Houthakker, 1996, pp.240/41).

    Today clearinghouses are central institutions for keeping the market flowing despite network related complexities such as anonymity and speed. Both factors makes it impossible to determine the contextual background of the data provided on, say, the Reuters screens. This is especially important for third, forth and fifth level tradings where the determination of the original source would be so complex that it would be impossible to deal derivative instruments at all.

    The largest private sector payments network in the world is Clearing House Interbank Payments System (CHIPS) in N.Y.C.. About 182,000 interbank transfers valued at nearly $1.2 trillion are made daily through the network17. This represents most of the exchange of the capital markets within N.Y.C. (From the webpage of the Federal Reserve Bank of NYC)

    Even though the institution of the clearinghouse is more than 120 years old, its central position is directly related to the nature of computer networks. With the growth of the networks the number of clearinghouses (and other similar institutions) is rising. Clearinghouses can be viewed as one of the first private, global legal institutions that regulate the communication in a supposedly deregulated market (Sassen, 1996)18.

    Central network-related characteristics of the clearinghouse are:

    • They are cooperative. They are backed by a number of private firms and their common interest to keep the markets fluid.
    • They work through convenience. As a private body they can, ultimately, not resume exclusivity. But since it is structurally necessary to have such institutions they emerge as quasi monopolies that can claim "official" character. Trying to circumvent them is de-facto impossible.
    • They are specific and independent. Clearinghouses regulate only a tiny, but central, element of the overall communication of the financial market, the final execution of the deal. Everything else, the background, the arrangement, the conditions, and the approval of the deal are regulated by completely separate bodies, such as the private Reuters network or individual contracts.
    • A number of institutions are distributed around the world, each with its specific definition. There is no overall ultimate clearinghouse, each one is ultimate by itself.
    • They are emergent. Clearinghouses grow in scope and in numbers according to the long term development of the financial markets without central planning about closely interrelated with the overall structure.

    4. The nature of networks


    4.1. Networks as environment


    Financial networks provide their own complete environment. They are content and context at the same time. The surrounding larger social and economic environment is structurally separated and its relevance is relevance is assesed regarding whether it has the ability to invade the closed universe of the financial market, for example in form of new that are regarded as important. But which information is important and which is not is decided within the markets and has nothing to do with the 'value' of the information as such. The context of the market defines the content of the information. If everyone expects a company, or a country, to report huge losses, then the news of moderate losses can boost the price or currency, in contrast, if everyone expects the opposite then the same piece of information can have a devastating influence on the market value.

    As a complete environment the (financial) networks are fully self-referential, or to quote Marshall McLuhan: "New media are not bridges between man and nature, they are nature" (quoted in, McLuhan, Zingrone, 1995 p.272). Everything that counts is what happens within the networks. What are the other participants doing? Since the direct connection to other environments, or subsystems, is broken, the ultimate determination takes place within the markets themselves. Evidently, the markets react very fast on new information and the connection to political and economic events is almost immediate. Nevertheless, it is indirect. The markets as a closed system react on news because its active elements, the dealers, expect each other to react and try to react before the others. What the others plan to do is the most important information. John M. Keynes described this structure is his famous beauty contest analogy:

    "Professional investment be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick, not those faces he finds himself the prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view. it is not the case of choosing those which, to the best of one's judgment, are really the prettiest, not even those which average opinion genuinely thinks the prettiest. We have reached the third degree, where we devote our intelligence to anticipating what average opinion expects average opinion to be. And there are some, I believe, who practice the fourth, fifth and higher degrees." (Keynes, 1936 p.156)

    4.2. Face value and cooperation


    Information has to be taken at face value. Its reality is as flat as the screen where the data is displayed, its only relation is to other facets of the same flatness, the other screen to which every screen is connected. What makes the information different is the speed of their circulation. In such an environment news and rumors become equally important. And sometime rumors become even more important than news, since they promise to predict what might be news tomorrow to everyone. And that is the most valuable information and can actually become the cause of tomorrow's news. If some of the major dealers expect a currency to loose value, they will start to sell it, which will be seen be others as a sign that the value of this currency is falling and the result is that, if many start to sell, the value of the currency is actually sinking.

    For Jean Baudrillard this reversal in the relationship of sign and object is the principal characteristic of post-modernity. In his sombre prose he analyzes that the simulation is no longer 'representational imaginary' "rather, genetic miniaturisation is the dimension of simulation. The real is produced from miniaturised units, from matrices, memory banks and command models ... It no longer has to be rational, since it is no longer measured against some ideal or negative instance. It is nothing more than operational." (Baudrillard, 1983, p.32)

    At first hand strange and unenvisioned in the gloomy metaphors of Baudrillard, the effect of that reversal is cooperation. Since networks are tools and environment at the same time, everyone who uses the tools has a certain need to maintain the environment19. This does not imply any idyll, the cooperation is only on the level of the environment, and not within the environment. There are exceptions to this rule, evidently.

    Networks function efficiently when information can actually be taken at face value. To guarantee this they have to be structurally separated from other environments. In this regard the institution of the clearinghouse can be read as a one trillion dollar per day cooperative buffer against the invasion of external context. The clearinghouse provides the world economy's most substantial resources, ultimately the funds of the most relevant firms in the markets, to guarantee the constant flow within the networks, uninterrupted by external defaults which would be translated directly into the network and not only indirectly through the interpretation of the players. This direct impact would destroy the face value of the information. If the financial networks are the global brain, or parts of it, then the clearinghouse is the helmet that prevents the direct, not translated impact of the hammer of bankruptcy from crushing the skull. Without this helmet the speed in which the information would be allowed to flow would be much slower.

    In the network environment, then, the condition of staying a member of the network is to provide information that can be taken at face value. The position of a player is determined by the information he, she, or it delivers to the other players, the faster and the more accurate it is, the more relevant the source becomes. Since everyone is connected with everyone reliable information gets delivered to the environment as such. The connectiveness forces even in the most competitive environments a certain form of collaboration. What seems paradoxical is the nature of the network, it needs collaboration to stabilize itself, building the stage for competition at the same time.

    4.3. Convergence


    This connectiveness converges not only cooperation and competition, but also the discreteness of action and reaction, event and news into the continuity of a flow. The dealers see instantly what others do, which builds the basis of their actions which is fed back to the other dealers who base their decisions upon that. This constant feedback eliminates the separation of events (before) and news (after) emerging into a constant presence. In a constant presence predicting the future is the most important task. Self-learning systems that can feed upon themselves, learning through feedback become the adequate models to interpret the patterns of that presence and its inherent future.

    It is only logic that such a convergence is also expressed organizationaly. Reuters does not only provide the news and information about the financial markets to the markets but it also provides the tools for the markets to make the information. Consumer of news and producer of news converge and the network displays instantly to everyone what everyone else does. Or, in other words, its only content are the users.

    4.4. The paradox of control


    A network's connectiveness is not only defined by its ability to connected people over time and space barriers, its second characteristic is its tendency to integrate formerly independent elements on a higher level of abstraction. Abstraction allows the construction of larger areas of control, in the financial markets through instruments such as derivatives, but these instruments become at the same time less stable and the environment less predictable. There are simply to many factors to really exercise control. Increased abstraction and the possibilities to influence ever greater area create a paradox of control.

    "The paradox of scale and control is most visible in the financial sector where heavy investment in technologies designed to enhance the predictability and responsiveness has been blamed for exacerbating instability: when a multitude of different and competing actors seek to improve their control capacities, the result at the level of the system is a breakdown of control. What is rational at the micro level becomes highly irrational at the macro level." (Mulgan, 1991 pp. 28/29)

    With the number of connections and the speed of communication rising the predictability and controllability of the system as such is decreasing.

    5. Outlook: development without control?


    The interconnected environment is driven by an internal logic that is not reducible to the planning of the small number of centers. Even though there are clearly visible major nodes within the network they are not in a central command position. The are in the same way interconnected to the network at large as any smaller node.

    On the other hand, development is not random. It is the result of great number of planned efforts to survive in that environment. Each environment rewards its members if they use specific strategy to seek that survival, these strategies, or rules of conduct, evolve over the time out of interaction of the members who constantly feed back the success of their actions regarding the reaction of the other members of the network to readjust their own strategy.

    The two paradoxes of networks, control/chaos and cooperation/competition, produce two completely equally adequate ways to describe them. Form the inside, on the level of the usage they are complex and unpredictable, chaos and competition are dominating the picture. From the outside, on the level of effects, they are very predictable and unimodal, cooperation and control seem to be their prime features.

    6. Bibliography

    Apostolos-Paul, Refenes (1995). Neural Networks in the Capital Markets. New York: John Wiley & Sons

    Arrighi, Giovanni (1994). The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. London; New York: Verso

    Babe, Robert E. (ed.) (1994). Information and Communication in Economics. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers

    Baudrillard, Jean (1983). Simulations. New York: Semiotext[e]

    Eichengreen, Barry (1996). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press

    Eichengreen, Barry (ed.) (1985). The Gold Standard in Theory and History. New York: Methuen

    Hammond, Ray (1996). Digital Business : Surviving and Thriving on an On-Line World. London: Hodder & Stoughton

    Houthakker, Hendrik; Williamson, Peter (1996). The Economics of Financial Markets. New York, Oxford: Oxford University Press

    Kelly, Kevin (1994a). Out of Control. The New Biology of Machines, Social Systems and the Economic World. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley

    Kelly, Kevin (1994b). Cracking Wall Street. Wired Magazine, 2.07, July

    Keynes, John M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan

    Kindleberger, Charles P. (1989). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crisis, 2nd revised Edition. New York: Basic Books

    Kurtzman, Joel (1993). The Death of Money. How the Electronic Economy has Destabilized the World's Markets and Created Financial Chaos. New York: Simon & Schuster

    Lowell, Bryan; Farrell, Diana (1996). Market Unbound : Unleashing Global Capitalism. New York: John Wily & Sons, Inc.

    McLuhan, Eric; Zingrone, Frank (eds.) (1995). Essential McLuhan. Concord, Ont.: Anansi

    Mehta, Mahendra (1995). Foreign Exchange Markets. in Apostolos-Paul, Refenes (ed.) Neural Networks in the Capital Markets New York: John Wiley & Sons

    Millan, Greogory J. (1995). The Vandal's Crown. How Rebel Currency Traders Overthrew the World's Central Banks. New York, London, Toronto: Free Press

    Mills, Terence C. (1992). Predicting the Unpredictable. Science and Guesswork in Financial Market Forecasting. London: Institute of Economic Affairs

    Mosco, Vincent (1996). The Political Economy of Communication: Rethinking and Renewal. London: Sage

    Mulgan, Geoff (1991). Communication and Control, Networks and the New Economies of Communication. New York, London: Guilford Press

    Read, Donald (1992). The Power of News: The History of Reuters 1849-1989. Oxford: Oxford University Press
    Reich, Robert (1991). The Work of Nations. New York: Alfred A. Knopf

    Robins, Kevin; Webster, Frank (1988). Cybernetic Capitalism: Information, Technology and Everyday Life. in Mosco, Vincent; Wasco, Janet (eds.) The Political Economy of Information. Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press

    Sassen, Saskia (1996). Losing Control? Sovereignty in an Age of Globalization. New York: Columbia Press
    Sassen, Saskia (1994). Cities in a World Economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press

    Spivak, Gayatri C. (1987). Speculations on Reading Marx: After Reading Derrida. 30-62 in Attridge, Derek; Bennington, Geoff; Young, Robert (eds.) Post-structuralism and the Question of History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

    Toporowski, Jan (1993). The Economics of the Financial Markets and the 1987 Crash. Hants, UK; Brookfield VM: Edward Elgar Publishing Company

    Valdez, Stephen (1993). An Introduction to the Western Financial Markets. London: The Macmillan Press LTD
    Wriston, Walter (1996). The Future of Money; An Interview by Thomas A. Bass. Wired Magazine, 4.10, Oktober

    Wriston, Walter (1992). The Twilight of Sovereignty. How the Information Revolution is Transforming Our World. New York, Toronto: Maxwell Macmillan

    Endnotes

    1 The case is different for money itself. This has always to be tied to something, either to something physical as gold or something imaginary as a "system of belief and confidence" (Hammond, 1996, p.148).

    2 No other sector in society has been so radically transformed by new technology as the financial markets. No other sector has gained so much power in the last two decades. No other sector has this profit rate. It is popular in the financial literature to describe this transformation with an analogy to the impact of the atomic bomb. (Lowell, Farrell 1996 p.2; Millan, 1995 p.vii)

    3 The financial markets are in many ways fragmented. In this paper I will use examples from different areas to exemplify characteristics of the markets as a whole even though there are substantial variations between the different segments.

    4 Culture is understood in a very broad definition as the way humans interact and the artifacts, institutions and values into which these interactions stabilize.

    5 I would like to thank Jesse Hirsch for editing my paper and helping me mastering the finer details of the English language

    6 Gold standard means that the government guarantees that each bill can be exchanged against a fixed and predetermined amount of gold. After W.W.II only the US $ guaranteed to such an exchange. But since all other major currencies were tied to the dollar, the gold standard of the dollar was the de facto gold standard of the western world.

    7 The term Eurodollar is slightly misleading since all foreign-held US $ outside the US, whether they are in Europe or not, are called Eurodollars.

    8 It is generally difficult to estimate such figures precisely because neither is the term 'financial markets' sharply defined nor the concept of 'working in' these markets. There is a large gray zone of subcontracted and supporting services where people work for but not in the institutions that make up the markets.

    9 This estimate is based on figures from the 1995 Annual report of Reuters. It is the number of institutions accessing the Reuters' instruments for dealing. In regard of the central position of Reuters in financial markets one can assume that virtually every institution that deals in these markets is also a Reuters customer.

    10 Semi-public in the sense that the access only restricted by the access fees.

    11 This instrument was launched in 1992. It enables all traders linked to the product to see the best buy or sell price for a currency pair simultaneously. This automatic, anonymous service matches bid and offer orders using a central computer, verifying that the counterparts have sufficient and mutually acceptable credit.

    12 A market is regard as truly global not only when it reaches all national markets but when there are no regulatory or other differences between those national markets.

    Therefor, constitutive elements of a truly global market are:
    - every player can access to the same information
    - every player uses the same skills and techniques
    - risks are assessed the same way
    - the infrastructure needed is in place in very national market
    - all participants view the market as global, instead of international
    - there are no (national) restrictions
    - no government is able to control pricing
    (Lowell, Farrell, 1996, pp.36/37)
    In this sense truly global means the geographic component is irrelevant.

    13 There are two more parties involved in foreign currency exchange, tourists and governments (e.g. payment for US troops overseas). But the amounts they move are so small that they have no influence on the exchange rate. (Valdez, 1993, p.126)

    14 Example: A dealer buys for 5m an option on an asset worth 100m. If the assets becomes worth 110m at the time the option can be exercised, then the dealer buys it at the prearranged price of 100m and immediately resells it for 110m. The revenue is 10m. He paid 5m for the option to do so, earning the dealer a profit of 5m which equals 100% of the original investment. On the other side, if the price of the asset moves to 99m (-1%) then it makes no sense to buy them for 100m. The option, originally worth 5m, becomes worthless.

    15 The conceptual background of this inability to define the independent variable is the insight that, potentially, everything can be connected with everything. That the environment of the financial markets is not vertically derived from the 'real' economy, but that is forms a vertical, interconnected network.

    16 It is not surprising that this institution was founded in Chicago in the late 19th century. At this time, Chicago was the trading place for most of the commodities of the Mid West, mainly agricultural products. Since they are usually delivered only once a year, at the time of the harvest, new dealing instruments were introduced, such as futures, where a farmer and a dealer could agree on a price and delivery in advance. These new ways of dealing required new regulations.

    17 An example how it works: suppose a London bank wants to transfer $1 million from its account at one New York correspondent bank "A," to an account at second New York correspondent bank "B." Banks "A" and "B" are both CHIPS participants.
    Bank "A" verifies the London bank's message and prepares to enter it into CHIPS. The CHIPS computer verifies the transaction and makes a permanent record of the transaction and makes appropriate debits and credits for the CHIPS records. When bank "B" receives a CHIPS credit message for one of its respondents, bank "B" notifies the bank that the funds are being credited to its account.
    Immediately following the closing of the CHIPS network at 4:30 p.m. (Eastern time), the CHIPS computer produces a settlement report showing the net debit or credit position of each participant. When this procedure has been completed, the Clearing House transfers those funds via Fedwire out of the settlement account to settling participants with net credit positions. The process usually is completed by 5:45 p.m. (Eastern time).
    To sum it up, the execution of all tradings, the total of $ 1.2 trillion daily turnover, takes less than 90 minutes.
    The example is from http://www.ny.frb.org/pihome/fedpoint/fed36.html

    18 Clearinghouses are a striking example that deregulation does not mean that the number of regulations is decreasing but that the power to regulate is transferred from the nation state to the market place.

    19 The same could be said regarding the natural environment in general. But there are principal differences. The main differences are the fragility and speed of networks that make their breakdown a comprehensible reality. They are man made and therefore easily destroyed by man. Cooperation is needed even for short term gains.


    End of document